Friday, January 18, 2013

Happy 2013?

By Don Alexander, MBA
Associate, RSD Solutions Inc.
Mr. Alexander also lectures at NYU and SunySB

Financial market quiescence has removed pressure for immediate policy action on the Eurozone crisis. Charles Wyplosz, in a recent (Jan. 4th) VOXEU communique, argues that while important repairs were made in 2012, there are serious problems ahead. Things will have to get worse before they get better, especially if politicians delay making critical decisions.

The situation of the Eurozone is now becoming clearer. This note lists ten observations and draws five consequences. The bottom line is that, even though some important steps were taken in 2012, the most difficult ones still lie ahead.

The observations for the Eurozone problems include: 

·       Prolonged austerity policies have contractionary effects.

·       Debt reduction is a very long process; that takes years or decades

·       The debt-to-GDP ratio is best reduced through sustained nominal GDP growth.

·       In a fiscal union whereby an agency would both coordinate national fiscal policies to achieve a good Eurozone policy mix and organize transfers from the countries that achieve their lowest unemployment rates.

·       The crisis has delivered a surprising degree of wage flexibility and labor mobility.

·       The long-hoped-for awakening of the ECB has produced several miracles, especially a major relaxation of market anguish.

·       In most Eurozone countries, structural reforms are as needed now as they were before the crisis.

·       Banks are at the heart of a negative feedback loop: bank holdings of their national public debts.

·       Massive forbearance has allowed many banks to not fully account for the losses that they incurred in 2007-8, if they deleverage, which leads to a credit crunch, which slows growth down. As the recession spreads and deepens, bank loan quality is quickly deteriorating. This second diabolic loop links banks and the real economy.

·       The ECB is the lender of last resort both to banks and to governments.  This involves massive moral hazard. Moral hazard can be sharply reduced with appropriate institutional measures.

What are the policy implications from these observations? Wyplosz draws five different lessons:

  • Sustained real growth should be the number one priority.
  • Austerity policies must stop, now.
  • Growth will not return unless bank lending is adequately available (1) they must stop lending to their own governments, and (2) they must be shut down if they are unable to raise the capital needed for them to lend to the private sector. But their governments may not have the resources to carry out resolution.
  • The ECB may act as lender in last resort to banks and governments, but who will bear the residual costs, as current temporary facilities are too small?
  • The only remaining option is public debt restructuring, a purging of the legacy.

This will lead to bank failures. This means that debt reductions must be deep enough to make it possible for governments to then borrow, to shift to expansionary fiscal policies and to bail out the banks that they destroyed in the first place, in effect undoing the negative feedback loop. The ECB is the only institution in the world that can help out. That means massive losses on its balance sheet and therefore negative capital, which is not an economic problem but a potentially severe political one.

There is no easy option for the Eurozone after three years of deep mismanagement. Governments will not accept drastic action unless forced to. This means another round of crisis worsening and since the eventual costs are rising as public debts keep growing, the best hope is that it happens in 2013 rather than in 2014.  It will be a challenging period for risk management.

www.voxeu.org/article/happy-2013

Wednesday, January 16, 2013

A Better Way to Design Global Financial Regulation

By Don Alexander, MBA
Associate, RSD Solutions Inc.
Mr. Alexander also lectures at NYU and SunySB

Economists, central bankers and politicians are pushing for effective implementation and better coordination of the new financial regulations currently under construction across the globe.  The authors, Viral Acharya and Sabri Oncu, argue in a recent VOXEU communique (Jan. 14th) that at a time of crisis, financial regulators were forced to act on systemically important assets and liabilities, rather than focus on the individual financial institutions holding them.  A key turning point towards better regulation will be when we recognize the need for such action ahead of time, building the essential infrastructure that reduces incentives for excessive risk-taking.

A key regulatory failure behind the global financial crisis was the focus on individual rather than collective or systemic risk of financial institutions. Importantly, the main focus is not on all financial institutions as a collective group, but only on those financial institutions to be deemed systemically important.  This will divert risks to the weakly regulated or unregulated parts of shadow banking.

Ignoring the issue of regulatory arbitrage and shadow banking, the progress on the global implementation of new financial regulations has been slow.  The main reason behind this is that many systemically important financial institutions operate across borders, but there are different styles and interests of regulators in different countries.

There is a better alternative and to design global financial regulation: one is to harmonize existing regulations and is reasonably immune to the risks posed by shadow banking evolution.  The focus on individual institutions create problems on the liability side when a counterparty defaults and could create a run on other entities.  Conversely, fire sales of assets can force collateral damage on other holders of such assets.

The point is to regulate all institutions holding such assets, regardless of their home country or whether they are deemed systemically important.  It would require dedicated utilities, such as ‘clearinghouses’ for derivatives.  These utilities, operating at the level of individual assets and liabilities would deal with defaults by ensuring orderly liquidation of positions. And, recognizing that such liquidation poses significant risks, there would be limits imposed on the risk of positions in the first place such as margin requirements.

The Financial Stability Board can coordinate at the global level the setting up of such utilities and can harmonize and enforce risk management standards.  This is easier than designing regulations that operate at the level of individual institutional forms.  If shadow banking develops newer assets and liabilities, then, newer utilities would be introduced in the financial sector.  The Federal Reserve, the Bank of England and the ECB set up facilities to avoid financial collapse during the financial crisis.  These facilities were set up for systemically-important financial instruments.

Stated differently, financial regulators around the globe were forced in the midst of a crisis to act on systemically important assets and liabilities, rather than just on individual financial institutions holding them.  The key is to recognize the need for such action ahead of time and build the essential infrastructure to ensure that excessive risk-taking is discouraged and markets know that regulators have an orderly resolution plan.  This would help simplify risk management.

www.voxeu.org/article/better-way-design-global-financial

Tuesday, January 15, 2013

Limited Progress on Banking Reform and What is Needed

By Don Alexander, MBA
Associate, RSD Solutions Inc.
Mr. Alexander also lectures at NYU and SunySB

Banking regulators, supervisors and politicians have failed to do their job for implementing reforms to limit damage from financial crises.  This failure of political will enabled stakeholders to pursue bad practices, and suggests a roadmap for reform.  Enforcing a reform agenda marked by simplicity is plausible, and would avoid much of the collateral damage that comes from many hundreds of pages of complex, costly and misguided mandates that typically act as substitutes for credible reform.

This is a case presented by Charles Calomiris in a recent VOXEU communique (Jan. 8th) called Meaningful Bank Reform and Why it is Unlikely to Happen.

He notes that regulators and supervisors consistently failed in three key areas: (1.) they did not measure banks’ risks accurately or capital buffers needed to absorb losses; (2.) they failed to enforce the capital requirements and identify bank losses; and (3.) they failed to design or enforce intervention protocols for timely resolution of the affairs of weakened banks.

The failure to prevent the crisis was not a failure of thinking, but a failure of will on the part of our political system.  Politicians and regulators have found it expedient to offer hidden subsidies for risk taking to bankers through safety net protection and ineffectual regulation.  Overall, the cause for pessimism is a simple reason: politicians don’t really have strong incentives to solve the problems of banking regulation; they have strong incentives to pretend.

Deficiencies are supposedly remedied by ever-more-complex sets of rules for measuring risk, by granting increased supervisory discretion to a variety of new government officials with varying mandates, by scores of new research initiatives pursued by increasingly fragmented research and supervisory divisions at central banks and supervisory agencies, by the creation of new international study groups. Is it too cynical to see this exponential increase in complexity of rules, and of the regulatory and supervisory authorities charged with designing and enforcing them, as deliberately designed to reduce accountability by dividing responsibility and by making the regulatory process less comprehensible to outsiders?

The need is not for more complex rules, and more supervisory discretion, but rather for rules that: (1.) are meaningful in measuring and limiting risk; (2.) are hard for market participants to circumvent; and (3.) are credibly enforced by supervisors.  These qualities are best achieved by constructing simpler rules that are grounded in an understanding of the incentives of market participants and supervisors.

The keys to effective reform in all these categories are, recognizing the core incentive problems that have encouraged excessive risk taking and ineffective regulation and supervision, and designing reforms that are ‘incentive-robust’ – that is, reforms that are likely not to be undermined by the self-seeking regulatory arbitrage of market participants, or the self-seeking avoidance of the recognition of problems by supervisors.

This program of reform would be effective in addressing the real challenges that threaten the financial system.  This approach must avoid the collateral damage that comes from the many pages of complex, costly and misguided mandates that are substitutes for credible reform. Politicians dislike simple ideas, based on observable criteria, since they work by removing the discretionary control that politicians, bankers, and regulators enjoy and abuse over the enforcement of regulatory standards. Overcoming that challenge will require more than good economic thinking and a simpler, credible approach for risk management

www.voxeu.org/article/meaningful-banking-reform-and-why

Monday, January 14, 2013

Safe Assets, Complex Networks & Systemic Risk

By Don Alexander, MBA
Associate, RSD Solutions Inc.
Mr. Alexander also lectures at NYU and SunySB

The notion that the global economy could be faced with a shortage of safe assets has become a significant theme in recent policy debates. Safe assets are a cornerstone of modern financial systems. They provide a reliable store of value, serve as collateral in financial transactions, and serve as a pricing benchmark. Should they disappear, the danger is that the financial system itself might crumble. Markets for collateralized transactions (repos) would collapse; financial institutions would have difficulties meeting their prudential requirements, and the pricing and well-functioning of riskier segments of the financial system could be derailed altogether. Without a safe anchor, the financial system would experience greater systemic instability.

This is a link that Pierre-Olivier Gouchinas and Olivier Jeanne seek to examine in a recent BIS WP (Dec. 2012) called Global Safe Assets.  The authors suggest a link between macroeconomic shortages of safe assets and some of the most disturbing features of our recent global financial history.  This shortage has depressed  world interest rates and fueled ‘global imbalances.’ This growing external demand for safe stores of value also proved a powerful stimulant for US and European financial markets as they manufactured large amounts of ‘private label’ safe assets through the securitization of riskier assets .

The global financial crisis arose when many of these ‘private label’ safe assets –perceived as safe because they were bestowed with a AAA rating– lost that quality. The sudden realization that many of the safe assets undergirding the entire financial system were of questionable value led to a ‘sudden financial arrest’. In the subsequent unraveling, most of these ‘private label’ safe assets disappeared. In the euro area, the strains associated with the crisis quickly morphed into concerns about the safety of sovereign debts, as governments simultaneously tried to shore up their financial sector and to sustain domestic economic activity. This led to further shrinkage in the global supply of safe assets at the same time that deleveraging financial institutions, panicked investors and anxious reserve managers all tried to fly to safety.

In short, macroeconomic shortages of safe assets can create financial instability. Crises, when they occur, further exacerbate the shortage that gave rise to it. Policy responses designed to cope with the crisis such as liquidity injections and monetary easing prolong the conditions for financial instability and delay the necessary balance sheet adjustment of households and financial institutions.  However, it ignores that the global economy also exhibits powerful stabilizing mechanisms such as a decline in the natural real interest rate, resulting from the excess demand for stores of value.

Monetary policy plays two important roles.  First, it will need to accompany the decline in the natural rate that occurs when the scarcity of stores of value becomes more acute. Second, monetary policy can also play an important role as a backstop for public securities.

The more interesting question lies in the composition of this asset supply and how to make it less ‘fragile.’ It is of the essence of a safe asset that it cannot become unsafe. The definition of safe assets has a key impact on the financial sector and should not be left entirely to the private sector.  The authorities should commit themselves to a clear definition of safe assets and back it with a policy regime that makes those assets credibly safe. Claims on the private sector are inherently risky and should stay so to limit moral hazard: for this reason they may not provide a good basis to produce safe assets. Besides money, government debt remains the best candidate for the status of safe asset. Central banks, furthermore, have a role to play in making government debts safe.

The previous analysis has a number of implications for the global economy. First, it suggests that global banking will naturally take place in the currency that offers an appropriate supply of safe assets. This role is fulfilled now primarily by the US dollar.  Second, there are important distinctions to be made between inside and outside liquidity and between public and private liquidity. In tranquil times, these different forms of liquidity are close substitutes and trade at similar prices. In times of global stress, all liquidity dries up, as counterparty risk rises. The only relevant form of liquidity comes from the public sector, through liquidity injections of the monetary authorities, or the injection of public funds in troubled financial institutions.

The global scarcity of safe assets is bound to increase as the global demand for safe assets—-tied to global economic growth—-outstrips the supply—tied to US economic growth and fiscal sustainability. This might be resolved by the emergence of new safe assets. One question is how multiple safe assets will compete on a global stage. This can be done by increasing the supply of safe assets, a multipolar world will remove some sources of financial instability. However, the feedback loop that supports the status of safe assets may also turn vicious, and the arbitrage between safe assets might generate rather than reduce volatility. In other words, the transition to a more multipolar world may not be monotonous, nor smooth, if and when it occurs. A multipolar world may therefore itself need a global backstop such as the IMF.

http://www.bis.org/events/conf120621/gourinchas_paper.pdf