Friday, February 8, 2013

Weather

By Rick Nason, PhD, CFA
Partner, RSD Solutions Inc

I have been on four different flights today – however I have not moved even 10 feet.  All of the flights that I have been booked on have been cancelled due to the weather.  I have an important set of meetings tomorrow with a client, and thus I booked a flight that went on the previous day – in part because I know these weather related travel delays occur. 

I have also looked at alternative routes, but as the destination city is where the weather delay is occurring that is not helping.

Experienced travelers know that the weather creates travel havoc.  Also, although they never get used to the weather related travel disruptions, experienced travelers also know that there is little that you can do about except make the best of it (for instance by getting caught up on your blog writing).

In risk management, we also have our equivalents of weather.  There are risk issues that we can plan for and that we can make contingency plans for, but in the end we ultimately sometimes just have to let things take their course.

Thursday, February 7, 2013

Macroeconomics and the financial cycle: Hamlet without the Prince?

By Don Alexander, MBA
Associate, RSD Solutions Inc.
Mr. Alexander also lectures at NYU and SunySB

Recently, the financial cycle has re-emerged as a key driver of the macroeconomy, but economic analysis has not caught up. Claudio Borio argues, in a recent VOXEU communique (Feb. 2nd), macroeconomics without the financial cycle is like Hamlet without the Prince. Economic analysis and policies – monetary, fiscal, and prudential – should account for the financial cycles, but more work is needed. The question to address the bust and balance-sheet recession that follow the boom deserves special attention.

Since 1980, it is difficult to understand business fluctuations and the corresponding policy challenges without understanding the financial cycle. This perspective was taken for granted from the 19th century and to the Great Depression; it barely survived in the post-war period; and it has been regaining ground, after the Great Financial Crisis.

The financial cycle is best viewed as the self-reinforcing interactions between perceptions of value and risk, attitudes towards risk, and financing constraints, which translate into booms followed by busts. These interactions can amplify economic fluctuations and possibly lead to serious financial distress and economic dislocations.

Recent BIS research suggests the financial cycle has several properties. First, its most parsimonious description is in terms of the behavior of private-sector credit and property prices; second, the financial cycle has a much lower frequency than the traditional business cycle; third, peaks in the financial cycle tend to coincide with episodes of systemic financial distress; fourth, the financial-cycle regularities inform the construction of real-time leading-indicators of banking crises that provide fairly reliable signals; fifth, financial-cycle information also helps construct real-time estimates of sustainable output that are much more reliable; and finally, the financial cycle depends critically on policy regimes.

Financial liberalization weakens financing constraints. Monetary-policy frameworks focused on short-term inflation control provide less resistance to the build-up of financial imbalances whenever inflation remains low and stable. And positive supply-side developments (e.g. globalization) fuel the financial boom while putting downward pressure on inflation. Financial cycles have become twice as long since financial liberalization (1980s) and have been especially virulent since the early 1990s.

Modeling the financial cycle requires capturing three key features: the booms should not just precede but cause the busts: busts are fundamentally endogenous; second, the busts should generate debt and capital stock overhangs – the natural legacy of the preceding unsustainable expansion; and, potential output should not just be identified with non-inflationary output: as the previous evidence indicates, output may be on an unsustainable trajectory even if inflation is stable.

The models need the following information: first, drop 'rational' (model-consistent) expectations; second, allow for state-varying risk tolerance; and last, capture more deeply the monetary nature of our economies: the banking sector does not just allocate given resources but creates purchasing power out of thin air.

During the boom, the key question is how to address the build-up of financial imbalances: first for prudential policy, it means containing the procyclicality of the financial system through macroprudential measures; second, for fiscal policy, it means extra prudence, fully recognizing the hugely flattering effect of financial booms on the fiscal accounts and large contingent liabilities are needed to address the bust; and third, for monetary policy, it means leaning against the build-up of financial imbalances even if short-term inflation remains subdued.

During the bust, the key question is how to address the balance-sheet recession that follows and becomes a serious flow problem, in the form of anemic output and expenditures.  The next step is crisis resolution and stabilization phase is critical and less well understood.  This phase is less understood in policy implementation: first for prudential policy, it means repairing banks’ balance sheets aggressively through the full recognition of losses, asset disposals, recapitalizations subject and reducing excess capacity necessary for sustainable profitability; second, for fiscal policy, it means creating the fiscal space needed to use the sovereign’s balance sheet to support private-sector balance-sheet repair while avoiding a sovereign crisis down the road; and third, for monetary policy, it means recognizing its limitations, risks and avoiding overburdening it.

The longer-term risk is that policies that fail to recognize the financial cycle will be too asymmetric and generate a serious bias over time. Failing to tighten policy in a financial boom but facing strong incentives to loosen it during the bust would erode both the economy’s defenses and the authorities’ room for maneuver. In the end, policymakers would be left with a much bigger problem on their hands and without the ammunition to deal with it – a new form of 'time inconsistency'. The root causes here are horizons that are too short and a failure to appreciate the cumulative impact of flows on stocks. This could entrench instability in the system over successive cycles.

Macroeconomics without the financial cycle is like Hamlet without the Prince: a play that has lost its main character. Post-crisis, both policymakers and academics are making efforts to understand and respond to the challenges the financial cycle poses. But these efforts are still falling short of the mark. The stakes are high; the road ahead a long one and a challenge for risk management.

www.voxeu.org/article/macroeconomics-and-financial-cycle-hamlet-without-prince

Tuesday, February 5, 2013

Super Bowl Ads

by Rick Nason, PhD, CFA
Partner, RSD Solutions Inc

While waiting for my flight this morning I looked through the Super Bowl ads.  As a Canadian, we only get to watch a small number of them during the game due to broadcast restrictions and the various international rights.  While looking through the ads I also looked at some of the comments that people posted, and also at some of the rankings for the ads. 

Some of the ads that I thought were boring or unconvincing had the opposite reaction with a lot of people.  Other ads that I struck a chord with me missed the mark with many of the commentators.  The incongruence in opinions however is totally rational.  Many of the ads that appealed to me were those targeted at an older audience – as I am older.  They were not targeted at a younger audience, which also tends to be the audience that is more likely to comment on bulletin boards.

Ads are designed for a target audience.  Thinking about the ads that appealed to me, I realized that they were trying to impress me, and not some 22 year old.  Likewise, the ad creators that were targeting 22 year olds do not give a hoot what I think about their ad.  Of course, the ads that try to please everyone generally wind up pleasing no one.

Monday, February 4, 2013

Theatre

by Rick Nason, PhD, CFA

Partner, RSD Solutions Inc

Is your risk management theatre?  It is a lot of show for the sake of showing stakeholders, creditors, regulators, rating agencies, or perhaps even your parents that you are doing something?  Or is your risk management grounded in solid managerial principles – focusing on increasing the probability and magnitude of good risk events happening while simultaneously working to decrease the probability and severity of bad risk events happening?  Is your risk management for show or for go?